pentru cap si pentru inima, peromaneste sau in original, fara prescriptie peromaneste
Traducere // Translate
Everything Trump and Republicans get wrong about trickle-down economics and Reaganomics
Gwynn Guilford
12-15 minutes
The sealing of America’s fiscal fate began in 1974, over cocktails.
As
afternoon faded to evening on December 4, Dick Cheney and a young
economist named Art Laffer shuffled into a booth at the Two Continents
restaurant in the iconic Hotel Washington—it had appeared in scenes from
the Godfather II just months earlier—two blocks from the US
Treasury department. Cheney was US president Gerald Ford’s deputy chief
of staff. He and his boss, Donald Rumsfeld, were looking for
alternatives to Ford’s plan to raise taxes 5%. Raising taxes was a bad
idea, said Laffer.If Ford really wanted to spur economic growth, and therefore government revenue, he should cut tax rates.
Cheney
wasn’t following. So Laffer grabbed a napkin, uncapped a Sharpie, and
drew two perpendicular lines and a blimp-shaped curve, halved by a faint
dotted line. With the tax rate on the y-axis and tax revenue on the
x-axis, the chart showed that, except at its bend, there were always two
points on the curve that generated the same amount of government funds:
a higher rate on a smaller base of economic activity, and a lower rate
on a larger base of economic activity.
“The conventional wisdom was: You want more revenue, you raise taxes,” Cheney recalled 30 years later,
in a Bloomberg interview reenacting that landmark 1974 meeting. “What
Art brought to the table with these curves is that if you wanted more
revenue, you were better off if you lowered taxes, to stimulate economic
growth and economic activity.”
This moment remains one of the
most famous legends of modern economic history. Its message—that tax
cuts pay for themselves—endures too. (Look no further than president Donald Trump’s budget plan for proof.)
This
is even more remarkable when you consider that, except in its very
vague suggestion that tax rates alone do not dictate tax revenue, Laffer’s curve is wrong.
Laffer’s curvy logic
Art and his chart in 1981, the year president Ronald Reagan put his ideas into action. (AP)Growth, argued Laffer, depends on how much people work and how much businessesinvest.
He believed both those things hinge on tax rates: the more income the
government takes away in taxes, the less motivated people are to work
and save (leaving businesses less money to invest).
The government
that thinks that raising taxes is necessary to pay for social programs
and other public services is short-changing itself, argued Laffer. When
tax rates are too high—in the “prohibitive range” of his chart—people
work less and businesses invest less, stifling growth and shrinking the
total amount of income available for the government to tax.
“We’ve been taxing work, output and income and subsidizing non-work, leisure and un-employment,” Laffer scribbled above his napkin chart, dedicating the napkin to Cheney’s then boss at the White House, Donald Rumsfeld. “The consequences are obvious!”
By letting people keep more of their earnings—encouraging work and investment—tax cuts fireupenterprise,
he argues. The growth that results broadens the country’s overall
income so much that, paradoxically, the government can bring in even
more revenue just by taxing at a lower rate. The
problem is, this tidy arc of cause and consequence doesn’t exist in the
real world. Sure, extremely high tax rates douse economic activity. But
there’s no reason to assume the relationship between tax revenue and
tax rates is perfectly U-shaped. And the equilibrium point at which a
government collects the most revenue possible without dragging down the
economy is impossible to know—and varies by country. There was no reason
in 1974—or, for that matter, now—to think the US was on the curve’s
“prohibitive” half (many economists put the inflection point for the highest marginal tax rate at around 70%). In fact, without detailed data, you can’t tell where on Laffer’s curve (or non-curve) you are at all.
Laffer’s
general idea of supply-side stimulus can sometimes work. Cutting tax
rates that primarily benefit rich people shifts wealth from the middle
classes to the rich. That might sound unfair, but in developing
countries where there’s not enough money to fund the investment needed
to spur growth, a Laffer-style policy could (temporarily) help stimulate
economic expansion by channelling wealth to potential investors.
But
this scenario is not applicable to the US. Private investment tends to
ebb and flow with the business cycle; when demand is feeble, so is
investment. Cutting taxes on America’s rich isn’t going to encourage
them to invest more—they already have plenty to spend and aren’t
spending it. Worse, by shifting wealth from middle class families to the
moneyed few—a group that is able to consume far less than the working
masses—this sort of policy suffocates demand even more. Slowing demand
drags on growth, causing debt and unemployment to rise.
The Laffer curve’s strange, seductive power
President Ronald Reagan signing the largest tax cut bill in US history at his California ranch in 1981. (AP/Charles Tasnadi)By 1977, Laffer’s idea was emerging as the core tenet of the increasingly popular “supply-side economics.”
At a time when stagflation was suffocating the US economy, and
Watergate had sullied the Republican Party, Laffer’s logic offered the
GOP an upbeat and understandable plan of action to give to constituents.
“It
has been said that the popularity of the Laffer curve is due to the
fact that you can explain it to a congressman in six minutes and he can
talk about it for six months,” economist Hal Varian once mused.
Even
in the late 1970s, most economists disagreed with Laffer’s assertion
that the US was in the “prohibitive” range of the curve. But Laffer’s
imagery overpowered the arguments of his critics. “To most
quantitatively-inclined people unfamiliar with economics, [Laffer’s]
explanation of economic inefficiency was a striking concept, contagious
enough to go viral,” says economist Robert Shiller, who studied the
concept’s persistent popularity in a recent paper (pdf).
But
the idea of tax-cutting your way to faster growth might still have
slipped into obscurity if not for Jude Wanniski, a Wall Street Journal
editorial writer and long-time Laffer disciple—who just so happened to
be the other guy at the Two Continents table alongside Dick Cheney.
Wanniski
named the image on the napkin the “Laffer curve”—a term he would also
use in his seminal 1978 treatise on supply-side economics, The Way the World Works. Wanniski’s
dramatic retelling of the serendipitous exchange between Laffer and
Cheney propelled the Laffer curve into the national spotlight—and caught
the eye of Ronald Reagan.
Mind you, Reagan wasn’t exactly a hard
sell. In fact, the former California governor saw himself as a living
testament to the Laffer curve’s logic. As a B-list Hollywood movie star
during the 1940s, Reagan faced the exorbitant tax rate of 91% (rates had
been hiked to fund America’s war effort). “You could only make four
pictures and then you were in the top bracket. So we all quit working
after four pictures and went off to the country,” Reagan once remarked.
Laffer’s supply-side logic served as the intellectual cornerstone for Reagan’s tax cuts, markinga
turning point in conservative ideology. Up until this point, Republican
orthodoxy was mostly focused on avoiding fiscal deficits. The GOP was
even fine with raising taxes as long as the government covered its
expenses. Economists and liberalpoliticians saw tax
cuts as a way to tuck some extra cash into workers’ pockets, encouraging
them to consume—which, in turn, boosted growth. But many old-school
Republicans scoffed at Laffer’s trickle-down theories. The most famous
example of this came during the GOP primary, when George H.W. Bush
dubbed Reagan’s supply-side ideology “voodoo economics.”
Reagan
persevered, however, and one of his first priorities as president was
putting Laffer’s ideas into practice. Shortly after taking office,
Reagan and Congress macheted the US tax code, bringing the top marginal
tax rate to 28%, down from 70%, and slashing corporate and capital gains
taxes. Higher growth was supposed to expand the tax base, compensating
the federal government for the revenues lost by the lower rate. Instead,
public debt exploded—and continued to grow throughout Reagan’s tenure. The Laffer curve had just failed its first big test.
The party of growth
Laffer chats with Republican governor of Texas Rick Perry in 2008. (AP/Harry Cabluck)Despite
the Laffer curve’s 1980s flop, Republicans have steadfastly refused to
give up on the theory. If anything, Laffer’s theory seems to have become
more popular among GOP candidates.
In 2004, president George W. Bush claimed his sweeping tax cuts would grow the economy and boosted tax receipts. Instead, tax revenue shrank.Undeterred, Republican candidates in the 2012 presidential election fawned over Laffer’s ideas (Michele Bachmann declared herself an “Art Laffer fiend“).
In the run-up to the 2016 Republican primaries, Laffer was once again
everyone’s go-to econ guy; on one particular Friday in April 2015, the
economist chatted with Rick Perry at 10am, Ben Carson at noon, Jeb Bush
at 1.15pm, Bobby Jindal at 5, and closing out the day dining with Ted
Cruz, reported the Washington Post.
President Donald Trump also consulted with Laffer during the 2016 race. “My tax cut is the biggest since Ronald Reagan,” Trump had crowed during his campaign.
And
with the debut of his new tax plan yesterday, we can see Laffer curve
principles once again in action. The president plans to pay for huge tax cuts for the rich with the growth these tax breaks will supposedly stimulate, even though history has shown time and again that swelling debt is the far more likely outcome.
The myth lives on
Dick Cheney and Donald Rumsfeld—central characters in the Laffer curve napkin myth—in 1975.If
the last four decades left any doubt that narrative is more powerful
than fact, the last four months have surely confirmed it. So it makes a
certain kind of sense that the idea of a man whose “genius was in
narratives, not data collection,” as Shiller put it, is shaping policy
once again.
Tellingly, even in a narrative as compelling as the
Laffer curve creation myth, it doesn’t seem to matter that the facts
don’t really line up. Economist
Art Laffer sketched a new direction for the Republican Party on this
napkin, illustrating his theory that lowering taxes increased economic
activity. Wall Street Journal editor Jude Wanniski popularized it, and
politicians Don Rumsfeld and Dick Cheney carried it out. (Courtesy of the National Museum of American History, American Enterprise exhibition)Here’s Cheney in 2014, reminiscing about the pivotal scribble in a Bloomberg video:
I
remember a white tablecloth and white linen napkins because that’s what
[Laffer] drew the curve on. It was just one of those events that stuck
in my mind, because it’s not every day you see somebody whip out a
Sharpie and mark up the cloth napkin at the dinner table. I remember it
well, because I can’t recall anybody else drawing on a cloth napkin.
Laffer
himself doesn’t recall the episode at all. “I personally don’t remember
the details of that evening we all spent together, but Wanniski’s
version could well be true,” wrote Laffer on page 291 of his 2010 book Return to Prosperity(which, incidentally, he co-wrote with one-time Trump economic adviser Stephen Moore).
“My
only reservation about Wanniski’s version of the story concerns the
fact that the restaurant used cloth napkins and my mother had raised me
not to desecrate nice things,” wrote Laffer. “Ah well, that’s my story
and I’m sticking to it.”
That’s not quite right, though. Wanniski has alwaysmaintained
the napkin was a paper cocktail napkin. This is particularly odd
because after pocketing it as a souvenir on that fateful night, Wanniski
donated the mythic Laffer curve napkin
to the National Museum of American History. That napkin is cloth,
however, not paper. Stranger still, beneath the curve, Laffer wrote, “To
Don Rumsfeld, at our Two Continents Rendezvous,” even though Wanniski insists Rumsfeld wasn’t at the Two Continents that night (Laffer, however, says Rumsfeld was present).
Even more puzzlingly, Laffer dated the napkin September 13, 1974—two
and a half months before the December meeting that Cheney and Wanniski
remember so clearly.
Could this legendary event have taken place twice?
Quartz asked Rowena Itchon of the Laffer Center about the discrepancy.
“Dr. Laffer drew on napkins when he had lunch with many people,” she
said.
Un comentariu:
Those with lower incomes tend to pay a higher proportion of their income in total taxes than the affluent do.
inheritance tax planners in Yorkshire
Trimiteți un comentariu